My initial analysis of the new rules suggests that Gabriele Marcotti was almost exactly on target with his understanding of the proposed new rules. The new rules only slightly modify the prior rules. They do not reopen football to unlimited spending by rich club owners, but they do make provisions to alleviate the impact of the rules in some situations and to allow clubs to come to UEFA with a long term business plan that will break even plan even though it involves interim losses. Before I discuss the actual changes, I should discuss several FFP developments that are not direct results of these rule changes, but can still have a significant effect on FFP.
MANCHESTER CITY AND PSG
Last season, Manchester City and PSG were subject to fairly
stringent restrictions on spending and European squad size based upon their
violations of FFP rules. These
restrictions were imposed pursuant to “voluntary settlement agreements” which
can be found here and here. Last month,
it was announced that Manchester City and PSG will not be subject to same level
of restrictions in the upcoming season.
These changes were not a direct result of the new FFP
rules. The changes are a result of the
clubs’ compliance with the terms of their settlement agreements. It was always contemplated that, if the clubs
behaved themselves, they would be subject to greatly reduced restrictions in
2015-2016. I cannot be sure that the
limitations on the two clubs have not been loosened more than originally
contemplated, but the fact that UEFA has banned Dynamo Moscow from European
Competition for a year (see here) should make it clear that the FFP rules are
still being enforced. Dynamo’s violation
was pretty extreme, however. They lost
over 302 million Euros when they were only allowed to lose 45 million. Dynamo reported compliant results, but the
adjustment to fair market value of their sponsorship deal with their “main
shareholder” added at least 257 million Euros to their losses.
THE COURT CHALLENGE
A second major change in FFP—unrelated to the new rules—arises
out of the recent, partially successful court challenge to the FFP
regulations. See here.
I have been unable to find a copy of the text of the
decision on line so I can only go by the news reports which may not be
completely reliable.
A court in Brussels referred the FFP challenge to the
European Court of Justice and imposed a stay on the FFP rules that would reduce
the maximum allowed loss for the current three year reporting period from 45
million Euros to 30 million Euros. UEFA
has appealed and claims that their appeal blocks the court’s ruling. As a result, I have no idea what FFP limit is
currently in effect. A cautious club
will try to keep their losses under 30 million Euros but it may not be
necessary. By the time it finally ends, this
case might change nothing or it might eliminate FFP entirely. As far
as I can tell, UEFA plans to continue to act as if it is fully in effect. However, they might have trouble imposing a
penalty on a club that loses between 30 and 45 million Euros.
THE NEW FFP RULES
The actual new rules are found in Annex XI and XII of UEFA’s
regulations. The new rules are less
definitive than the old rules. Even
though most things have not changed, the changes that were made leave a great
deal of room for interpretation. However,
the core requirement that a club must limit its losses over a three year period
to 30 million Euros remains unchanged.
VOLUNTARY AGREEMENTS
The rules now contain the brand new Annex XII covering
“Voluntary Agreements for break-even requirement.” These agreements can cover a period of up to
four years. However, not every club is
eligible. No club that has been a party
to a prior voluntary agreement, a discipline measure, or a settlement agreement
in the past three years can apply for a voluntary agreement. If I am interpreting this correctly that
means that there are 34 clubs that are currently ineligible to apply including
PSG, Manchester City, Dynamo Moscow, and Hull City.
Clubs must also fulfill one of three other criteria: they must have just qualified for European
competition in the upcoming season, but not the current season; they must have
fulfilled FFP requirements and qualified for European competition in the
current season; or, they must have undergone a change in ownership or control
in the past twelve months.
If a club wishes to seek such an agreement they must apply
by 31 December for the subsequent season.
For leagues on the normal European schedule this requires clubs to apply
before they know for certain that they have qualified for European Football. This deadline creates a logical conflict with
two of the three possible eligibility requirements. Only the change in
ownership criterion makes sense as the rules are written. Possibly, the club must apply by December 31
without knowing whether they are actually eligible, but the final decision on
the application will not be made until the end of the season when both FFP
results and European qualifications are known.
The application must include a detailed financial plan for
the future “based on reasonable and conservative assumptions.” Funds covering the projected losses must be
irrevocably committed in advance in a way that ensures the money will be there
when needed. UEFA gets to monitor the
club very closely.
It is not clear what sort of business plan UEFA is looking
for. A business plan that proposes to
spend huge amounts of money on football players and their salaries in order to
qualify for the Champions League will probably not be viewed as “based on
reasonable and conservative assumptions.”
If, for example, the owners of Crystal Palace, Aston Villa, West Ham,
West Brom, Bournemouth, Stoke, Newcastle, and Sunderland all came to UEFA with a business plan to spend their way into
the Champions League, those plans will probably not be approved. After all, we know that no matter how much
money these clubs spend, they are not all going to qualify for the Champion’s
League on a regular basis. Quite likely,
none of them will.
A business plan for the club to build a giant, new stadium
and use the vast increase in attendance to afford increased salaries in the
future might pass muster, but FFP already excludes spending on new or improved
stadiums so there would be no need to go to UEFA with such a business
plan. The same is true of a plan to
expand the youth system or training complex.
Those expenses also do not count under FFP.
A club that is heavily in debt might reasonably present UEFA
with a business plan calling for the owner (or, more likely, the new owner) to
pay off the club’s debts and thereby eliminate the ongoing burden of the
interest payments. This would allow the
club to spend more on transfer fees on a sustainable basis. If a club was paying 50 million Euros a year
in interest, UEFA might approve a business plan which called for the new
ownership to pay off those loans—in their entirety—in three years and, in
addition, contribute up to 50 million Euros a year to be spent on transfer fees
or salary while the loans are being paid off.
The club could characterize this spending as reasonable and sustainable because,
once the loans are paid off, the additional 50 million Euros would actually be
available to spend every year.
Of course, I do not run a football club. It may be obvious
to the people who run football clubs exactly how a club can spend vast sums of
money on players or other expenses that count against FFP in a way that would guarantee increased
future income even under ”reasonable and conservative assumptions.” The fact that I do not know how to do this
does not mean it is not possible.
EXCHANGE RATES
There is a new rule governing currency exchange rates. If a club fails the FFP test due to the
changes in exchange rates with respect to the Euro but would pass the breakeven
test in their local currency, the rules state that the club “should in
principle not be sanctioned.” There is
no indication as to when that principle would not apply. This rule will normally only help clubs whose
local currency has appreciated relative to the Euro. However, there might be times when
fluctuating exchange rates result in a club making payments or receiving income
at a time when the exchange rate has just changed for the worse.
MAJOR ECONOMIC PROBLEMS
There is now a provision that makes allowances for “Major
and unforeseen changes in the economic environment.” UEFA is
now permitted to take into account “quantifiable financial impact on the club
of extraordinary national economic events” assuming the events are both
temporary and beyond the normal fluctuation of the economy. One would assume, for example, that if Greece
left the Euro and, as a result, Greek clubs could not comply with FFP, they
would not be sanctioned—assuming the Greek clubs seeking to play in European
Football did not cause Greece to leave the Euro. Presumably, if this provision and FFP had
been in effect in 2008, there might have been a wholesale suspension of
sanctions for violating FFP in the face of the Great Recession. On the other hand, the continued poor
economic environment caused by the European’s elite’s insistence on austerity
will not be an excuse because, apparently, it is not temporary.
STRUCTURALLY INEFFICIENT FOOTBALL MARKETS
There is now a provision calling for the UEFA to consider
whether a club “is operating in a structurally inefficient football
market.” The football market is defined
as the territory of the UEFA Member Association. Structural inefficiency is determined yearly
based upon a “comparative analysis of the top division clubs’ total gate
receipts and broadcasting revenues relative to the population of the territory”
of the football market. The provision
provides no guidance as to what should be done with this information, but it is
fun to speculate.
I do not have access to all the information I need to evaluate
structural inefficiency, but I can take a couple of stabs at it using
information from the internet.
I found a link (here) to the total television
receipts for the top leagues in England, Spain, Germany, France, and Italy. I assume this was for the 2013-2014 season.
I divided the television receipts in euros by the
populations of the various countries.
England, not surprisingly, came in first at 32.9 euros per person. Spain came in second at 16.6 euros per
person. Italy, France, and then Germany
followed at 13.9, 7.4 and 6.1 euros per person respectively. To determine the actual figures for
structural inefficiency I would need to have the total gate receipts for each
league. I do not have that
information. Nevertheless, television
revenue is such a large part of the revenue stream in modern football that these
figures are not completely meaningless.
I also looked at Wikipedia and found a list of total revenue
for the leading sports leagues from around the world. (Here.)
I cannot vouch for its accuracy, of course. Wikipedia did not provide the numbers I
actually needed. My first calculation
using just television revenue was too under inclusive. The total revenue calculation is too over
inclusive because it includes commercial, player trading, sponsorship, and miscellaneous
revenue all of which are not included in UEFA’s determination of whether a
country has a structurally inefficient market.
I combined the Wikipedia income numbers with Googled population figures
and did the division myself. The
countries are listed in order of total revenue.
The revenue per person, (in euros) for various countries is:
England 68.4
Germany 28.2
Spain 41.4
Italy 27.9
France 22.7
Russia 6.2
Turkey 7.4
Holland 26.9
Portugal 28.4
Ukraine 6.2
Belgium 24.4
Scotland 37.2
Switzerland 21.1
All of these figures are high because they include too many
types of revenue. There is also no
guarantee that the revenue that does not count is consistent across the various
countries. The English, German, and
Spanish numbers, for example, should be lower due to relatively high
sponsorship and commercial revenue.
Portugal and Holland likely have relatively high player trading revenue. These numbers also do not account for the
fact that some leagues do not contain 20 clubs.
I have no idea how or if UEFA intends to account for that problem.
However UEFA might calculate the structural efficiency of a
football market, England is going to come out on top. This may mean that English clubs will be held
strictly to the FFP rules, but clubs from other countries will not. In particular, Russia and the Ukraine look like
strong candidates for more lenient treatment in future FFP calculations. This could be of particular significance to clubs
like Dynamo Moscow. Possibly, under
these rules, their spending, which was previously viewed as excessive would be
viewed as reasonable because of the structural inefficiency of the Russian
football market.
It is certainly not clear how much consideration structural
inefficiency will receive. If UEFA decides
that the French football market is exactly half as efficient as the English
football market does that mean that every French club should be able to make
its FFP calculations as if they had twice their actual revenue? Or will they only be allowed to pretend they have
twice their actual television and gate revenue?
Or will all French clubs be required to use the same bonus fake revenue
number based upon the average “missing” revenue for the typical club in Ligue
1? Or will UEFA just double the amount of
allowable losses? The answer is almost certainly none of the above, but that is
the problem. Right now no one can know
how the structural efficiency rules will work.
Possibly, UEFA will determine a normal level of structural
efficiency and only give special consideration to clubs from nations below that
level. Clubs from nations above that
level might all be treated the same so England would retain its advantage over
Italy and Germany, but not over Russia and the Ukraine.
Depending upon the methodology adopted by UEFA, English
clubs may face a tremendous disadvantage under FFP. Possibly, clubs from other countries will be
able to spend more than they earn whereas English clubs will not. Of course, such rules would only be a
significant advantage for those clubs owned by sufficiently rich people.
SUMMARY
The one certainty about these new rules is that they have transformed
the FFP rules from the certain to the uncertain. Prior to these changes (and the court
decision) the FFP rules, for all their complexity, could be clearly
explained. Now they cannot.
Take, for example, PSG.
They are currently almost completely out of the FFP doghouse except that,
because they have entered into a voluntary settlement agreement, they are not
eligible to request a voluntary agreement for three years. On the other hand, by any reasonable
standards that might be applied under FFP, the French football market is less
efficient than the English football market.
Can PSG expect to be treated more leniently in the future if they report
excess losses? How can they know in
advance since they are specifically excluded from seeking a voluntary
agreement? Can they argue that their
rich owner should be able to spend much more money than the rich owner of
Manchester City because of France’s structural inefficiency? Do the high French income tax rates factor
into this at all? I don’t think anyone
knows.
EFFECTS ON SOUTHAMPTON FC
It is not clear how or if these changes will directly affect
Southampton FC. Most likely they will
not have a very significant direct effect.
Southampton does not need to seek a voluntary agreement that involves
deficit spending because the Liebherrs have, in effect, already created and
followed such a plan. It is not clear if
there is a further “reasonable and conservative” spending plan that would
improve our situation.
On the other hand, the fact that voluntary agreements might
be available to help out other Premier League clubs could hurt us. In my prior post, I speculated that a new
rich owner might buy Aston Villa or Crystal Palace and put in huge sums of
money. A voluntary agreement would
explicitly allow this. However, it
appears likely that the new owners could not just put in money to pay
permanently higher salaries and transfer fees.
The increased spending must be sustainable from other sources by the end
of the voluntary agreement. That being
said, however, there may very well be ways that a famous old club like Aston
Villa or a London based club like Crystal Palace could use additional money to
permanently improve their financial position.
Depending on how the structural inefficiency language is
implemented, the new Financial Fair Play rules have the potential to greatly
weaken England’s position in European competition. Almost certainly, the structural inefficiency
rules will never help English clubs spend more money so they can only result in
benefits to clubs from other countries.
Of course, only those clubs with rich owners can benefit significantly
but there are rich owners of clubs in Russia, France, and the Ukraine who would
be willing to pay higher salaries and transfer fees even though they are losing
money. These clubs will be able to compete
with Southampton to sign good young players who want pay raises. Absent this change in the rules, once the new
TV contract kicks in, there would be only ten to 15 non-English clubs in Europe
that could compete with Southampton on wages.
That number could be significantly higher after the structural
inefficiency rules are applied.
Earlier this year I published an article entitled “Financial Fair Play: Friend or Foe?”
and concluded that, overall, FFP was Southampton’s friend. The answer is no longer clear. It still provides us with structural
advantages over most clubs throughout Europe. However, we will now, very
likely, have more competitors for the younger players with potential we seem to
want to sign.
No comments:
Post a Comment